-->

Learn about each of the loan on marketplace for business plan

Econ 101 and data (reply to David Henderson)

Econ 101 and data (reply to David Henderson)


I wrote a post for Bloomberg View about how Econ 101 needs more empirics (a favorite hobbyhorse of mine). They titled it "Most of What You Learned in Econ 101 is Wrong", which was a catchy but inaccurate title, since the word "wrong" is often unhelpful in describing scientific theories. For example, in the post, when writing about minimum wages, I wrote:
That doesn't mean the [Econ 101] theory is wrong, of course. It probably only describes a small piece of what is really going on in the labor market.
Sometimes you test a theory by looking at policy experiments, and what you find is that the treatment effect is in the direction the theory predicts, but the fit is poor - the percent of the variance explained is small. Does that mean the theory is "right", because the treatment effect is in the expected direction? Or does it mean the theory is "wrong", because the fit is poor? 

The answer, of course, is that "right" and "wrong" are not very descriptive, helpful adjectives in this situation. 

Anyway, there's the question of what to teach kids. Personally, I think that you should teach kids empirics no matter how good your theories are. High school physics and chem classes teach simple theories that are amazingly good at explaining a lot of real phenomena, but they also make sure to include lab experiments, so that kids can see for themselves that the theories work. And those are high school kids; college kids will be even more capable. There's no reason a college econ student shouldn't learn how to run regressions in 101.

But I think this becomes even more important when Econ 101 theories have poor fit. People tend to confuse treatment effects with goodness of fit, so if you teach kids a bunch of theories with poor fit but which get the sign of the treatment effect right, the kids will leave class thinking that these theories explain a lot more of the world than they really do.

This distinction is what some critics of my Bloomberg View post don't seem to get. For example, David Henderson writes:
In other words, in most cases there is a small, presumably negative, effect on employment. And presumably in the other cases there is a large effect. How, exactly, does this contradict the claims that Mankiw makes and that many of us teach in our equivalents of Econ 101? It doesn't.
In this case, the theories that Econ 101 books (like Mankiw's) teach tend to get treatment effects of the right sign - minimum wage hikes of the typical size probably do have a (very small) negative effect on employment. When Henderson says that the evidence doesn't "contradict" the theory, he means that the theory gets the sign of the treatment effect right.

The problem is that by emphasizing theory so much, and by relegating evidence to some brief asides, Econ 101 textbooks (and classes) will tend to trick kids into thinking that the theories have better fit than they do. When you make people learn a theory in detail, I think they naturally tend to believe that the theory has strong empirical fit unless they see evidence to the contrary. 

My other example was welfare. Studies show that the effects of the implicit tax rates in welfare programs like the EITC are very small. That's consistent with the relatively small Frisch elasticity of labor supply found in most micro studies. Even when you get welfare programs with very large implicit tax rates (100%!), the effect is generally not as big as you might expect (with 100% implicit tax rates, you'd expect AFDC to leave income unchanged, when in fact it does boost it somewhat). That implies that welfare affects labor supply through channels other than implicit tax rates and lump-sum payments. For example, Moffitt's survey of theory and evidence on traditional (TANF and AFDC) welfare programs discusses the idea of "welfare stigma". That's an idea that is difficult to explain with an Econ 101 type theory. But it may be important in practice. Thus, it is an idea that can only really be presented by looking at the evidence. (Note that this is a reason welfare programs are probably worse than the labor supply effects would imply!)

Now Mankiw doesn't disregard evidence, and Henderson gives an example of the way that Mankiw presents it:
Although there is some debate about how much the minimum wage affects unemployment, the typical study finds that a 10 percent increase in the minimum wage depresses teenage employment [by] between 1 and 3 percent.
Evidence is given, but it is relegated to a brief aside. The kids don't see the data for themselves. They don't learn how to work with it. They don't learn how the studies tested what they tested. They don't learn how to go verify for themselves how useful econ theories are.

To these kids, econ theories must seem like received wisdom. Even evidence, when presented only as a brief aside with no understanding of methodology, must also seem like received wisdom. Again and again, I talk to econ students who complain that they are expected simply to swallow what they are taught - unlike in their science classes. College kids are smart, and many of them are skeptical. They grow up learning that "science is the belief in the ignorance of experts." That doesn't tend to sit well with the kind of "received wisdom" approach that almost every intro econ textbook takes. Nor should it.

So while I definitely don't want to pick on Mankiw - his books really are excellent, my personal favorites - I think that most intro econ textbooks use this "received wisdom" style of theory-centric education with only brief references to empirical findings. That tends to result in students who either A) believe too much in the power of the theories they learn, or B) disbelieve and distrust econ in general. I see a lot of examples of both (A) and (B). Both of those outcomes do a disservice to the world.


from Noahpinion http://ift.tt/1MLjel2